Allocation Lifted for American Silver Eagle Bullion Coins

silver-eagle2

 

 

 

 

 

 

From: http://news.coinupdate.com/allocation-lifted-for-american-silver-eagle-bullion-coins-4857/

Effective Monday, June 1, 2015, the United States Mint’s American Silver Eagle bullion coins will no longer be subject to allocation. For the first time this year, authorized purchasers will be able to order the coins without limitations.

During periods when demand for bullion coins has exceeded the available supply, the United States Mint has utilized an allocation program to ration available coins amongst their authorized purchasers.  Allocation was used for the first time in 2008 when a surge in demand for physical precious metals exhausted the Mint’s supplies of gold and silver bullion coins. After brief suspensions, sales would be resumed on an allocated basis. Allocation was commonplace throughout 2009 and 2010 as production continued to fall short of market demand. The Mint has also used allocation for extended periods over the past two years.

The current allocation program has been in place since November 17, 2014. Leading up to the implementation of allocation, the US Mint had temporarily sold out of Silver Eagle bullion coins. The Mint had cited “tremendous demand” for the coins, following a drop in the market price of silver.

Allocation continued for the duration of sales of the 2014-dated Silver Eagles and also through the start of sales for the 2015-dated coins on January 12, 2015.

For the year to date, sales of American Silver Eagle bullion coins have reached 16,571,000 ounces.

The Currency Manipulation Charade

currency_dollar_052814thinkstock

 

 

 

 

From: https://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/currency-manipulation-legislation-tpp-by-stephen-s–roach-2015-05

NEW HAVEN – As the US Congress grapples with the ever-contentious Trans-Pacific Partnership – President Barack Obama’s signature trade legislation – a major stumbling block looms. On May 22, the Senate avoided it, by narrowly defeating – 51 to 48 – a proposed “currency manipulation” amendment to a bill that gives Obama so-called “fast-track” authority to negotiate the TPP. But the issue could be resurrected as the debate shifts to the House of Representatives, where support is strong for “enforceable currency rules.”

For at least a decade, Congress has been focusing on currency manipulation – a charge leveled at countries that purportedly intervene in foreign-exchange markets in order to suppress their currencies’ value, thereby subsidizing exports. In 2005, Senators Charles Schumer, a liberal Democrat from New York, and Lindsey Graham, a conservative Republican from South Carolina, formed an unlikely alliance to defend beleaguered middle-class US workers from supposedly unfair competitive practices. Stop the currency manipulation, went the argument, and America’s gaping trade deficit would narrow – providing lasting and meaningful benefits to hard-pressed workers.

While this argument has great emotional and political appeal, it is deeply flawed, because the United States has an insidious saving problem. America’s net national saving rate – the sum total of household, business, and government saving (adjusted for the depreciation of aging capacity) – currently stands at 2.5% of national income. While that is better than the negative saving rates of 2008-2011, it remains well short of the 6.3% average of the final three decades of the twentieth century.

Lacking in saving and wanting to grow, America must import surplus savings from abroad. And to attract that foreign capital, it has no choice but to run equally large balance-of-payments deficits.

So it is no coincidence that the US economy has a chronic current-account deficit. While this shortfall has narrowed from a peak of 5.8% of GDP in 2006 to 2.4% in 2014, it still leaves the US heavily dependent on surplus foreign savings in order to grow.

This is where the trade deficit comes into play. The US does not just pluck surplus foreign savings out of thin air. To attract the capital it needs, America must send dollars overseas through foreign trade.

And it is here that the currency manipulation argument falls apart. In 2014, the US ran trade deficits with some 95 countries. In other words, America does not suffer from a small number of bilateral trade deficits that can be tied to charges of currency manipulation by countries like China, Japan, Malaysia, or Singapore. Rather, the US suffers from a multilateral trade imbalance with many countries, and this cannot be remedied through the imposition of bilateral penalties such as tariffs.

Without fixing its savings problem, restricting trade with a few so-called currency manipulators would simply redistribute the US trade deficit to its other trading partners. In effect, America’s trade balance is like a water balloon – applying pressure on one spot would simply cause the water to slosh elsewhere.

Moreover, this approach could easily backfire. For example, assuming that there is no increase in domestic US saving, penalizing a low-cost producer like China for currency manipulation would most likely cause the Chinese piece of America’s trade deficit to be reallocated to higher-cost producers. That would be the functional equivalent of a tax hike on middle-class families – precisely the constituency that so concerns Congress. Further complications would arise from putting the verdict on currency manipulation – presumably dependent on some type of “fair value” metric – in the hands of politicians.

This is also the twist that underscores the ultimate congressional hypocrisy. The charge of currency manipulation is nothing but a foil for the US to duck responsibility for fixing America’s saving problem. Lacking any semblance of a strategy to boost savings – not just a long-term fix to the federal government’s budget deficit, but also meaningful incentives for personal saving – US politicians have turned to yet another quick fix.

In the end, there is no way around it: If Congress does not like trade deficits, it needs to address America’s saving problem and stop fixating on misplaced concerns over currency manipulation.

None of this is to argue that the US should ignore unfair trading practices. As a member of the World Trade Organization, the US has ample opportunity to use that body’s dispute-resolution mechanism to adjudicate major problems with its trading partners. And it has enjoyed success with this approach. What Congress cannot do is pretend that wrong-footed trade policy is the answer to its inability or unwillingness to refocus its domestic policy agenda.

Of course, it is always easier to blame others than to look in the mirror. But history has not been kind to major trade blunders. Just as the Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act of 1930 sparked a global trade war that may well have put the “great” in the Great Depression, Congressional enactment of enforceable currency rules today could spark retaliatory actions that might devastate the free flow of trade that a sluggish global economy desperately needs.

The US Senate was wise in rejecting this dangerous option. We can only hope that similar wisdom prevails in the House of Representatives. Currency manipulation legislation is one tragedy that can and should be avoided.

Further Testing ‘They Don’t Know What They Are Doing’

feddc

 

 

 

 

From: http://www.alhambrapartners.com/2015/05/27/further-testing-they-dont-know-what-they-are-doing/

by Jeffrey P. Snider

When looking toward what might be coming next from the FOMC, the reigning theme remains “they don’t know what they are doing.”  That sentiment applies, of course, retroactively to all the QE’s, Twists and badly implemented emergency measures on the way down, but attention is rightfully focused now on how to get to C.  Going from A to B already, there remains a large transitive step to take and the Fed is hoping to do so as an almost reactionary program to go back to A.  We know better.

This divergence starts with the plethora of “exit” tools that the Fed has amassed and even tested these past two years since they started toying with the idea.  The fact that the indication of “taper” was released almost as soon as QE4 got under way says a lot about just how much affection the FOMC has for all their dangerous stunts and experiments.  The problem, from their perspective, is that getting back to A requireseven more experimentation. That itself should suggest that the ultimate destination is not a revisiting of A but rather an unguided mission into uncharted C.

The momentous heraldry with which the reverse repo program (RRP) was first introduced stands now in stark contrast to the almost-contempt with which the FOMC as early as last July now holds it – with good reason.  Despite all the happy talk about “successful” tests, which somehow the standards for achieving that qualification are never released, the Fed at that July FOMC policy meeting made it clear that the RRP’s are an almost necessary-evil to them.  That was one reason they were given a $300 billion daily cap back in September.

Participants generally agreed that the ON RRP facility should be only as large as needed for effective monetary policy implementation and should be phased out when it is no longer needed for that purpose.

In other words, the FOMC intends to do as little as possible before scrapping it entirely.  Straight away, there are enormous problems with both parts of that summation.  Nobody has any real idea what “large as needed” may account, and there is surely major debate to come about “no longer needed.”  Taking the first part first, the FOMC originally decided on a relatively small RRP allotment, but has found out, under the qualification of “successful” testing mind you, that to achieve even their theoretical aims of raising rates in a conjunctive and orderly fashion would mean at least double the RRP’s.

More recent FOMC policy meetings have suggested that the academic economists have produced suitable regressions to that opinion, so much so that the FOMC has made it apparent that in all likelihood when the time comes (if it ever does) the RRP’s will likely come out totally uncapped.  Writing now for Credit Suisse, by way of Perry Mehrling’s blog (thanks to R Burch for pointing it out), Zoltan Pozsar has placed the theoretical likelihood of the RRP’s on an exit above $1 trillion.  As Mehrling points out, “that’s a pretty big disconnect” between what the Fed thinks on the affair and where more realistic assessments are heading.

Again, they don’t know what they are doing.

The issue of the RRP’s stands to connect these problems, from how big does it “need” to be in operation all the way to how long might it “need” to be around.  The Fed has decided small and very, very temporary, but the reality of the money markets and the paradigm shift argue very much against that wishful thinking.

The problem is that money markets stopped working in 2008 without any actual replacement at hand (A to B).  Dealers were primarily responsible for intermediating the structural inequities inherent in what is really an ad hoc global eurodollar system – it worked before because everyone thought it would.  The reason that dealers played such a primary role was because they could pillage freely the financial system through prop trading and gain-on-sale accounting.  There was too much profit (loosely defined in terms of GoS) in those to leave it alone, meaning that the eurodollar system on the way up was very much self-feeding and also the means by which it was all funded (certainly not boring and ancient deposits that ultimately limit financialism, and central bank activism).

The problem from A to B was that dealers got caught in the extremities of their own making, and instead of an orderly unwinding (which is never really a possibility) they simply exited.  The Fed took far too long to come to terms with this paradigm shift, preferring instead to see the global banking system as it was in 1930 or at best 1960, which is why money market breakdown turned into broad and global panic (of banks, by banks).  When it did finally act, what occurred was essentially the Fed remaking wholesale finance of its own balance sheet – not lender of last resort but market of last resort.

In the meantime, organic money markets have shriveled under the weight of this central bank intrusion.  There are reasons of Dodd-Frank and Basel, but also of QE and profits.

The trouble, then, longer term is what comes next when the Fed no longer acts as that market of last resort; the money markets must shift back to being a private affair.  The Fed, as noted above, wants to go back to A but dealer banks are essentially gone from money dealing and there isn’t any reason to expect that the end of ZIRP or QE will get them back into the habit – not without a total bypass of the Volcker Rule and conditions for renewal of “gain on sale” profits.  That last part will be very difficult with fixed income prices in general expected to move in the “wrong” direction as part of all this.

As Merhling aptly points out, Pozsar too, as the central premise, this shift is not just off ZIRP and the eventual winding down of QE’s already undertaken but actually a character change, over time, of the entire complexion of the money markets in the US and globally.  We went from A (dealer-led money markets) to B (central bank dead money markets) to a likely C of money market funds and other “cash pools.”  Pozsar’s Exhibit 7 illustrates this evolution very well.

That will lead, in Poszar’s interpretation, to not only a minimum $1 trillion RRP but one that dismisses any idea of “no longer needed.”

Eventually, we expect a massive and permanent overnight RRP facility, with government only money funds emerging as the ultimate home of money dealing. Money market funds in many ways are anathema to central bankers. But to regain control over short-term interest rates they deal with them directly: the “marriage” of necessity will occur. [emphasis added]

There are also grave concerns about shifting to a money fund paradigm, as well.  That would make the money system, if not global finance overall, much more like the shadow conduits that have been vilified (somewhat correctly) since 2007, and much less like the traditional and regulated banking system that everyone says they want.  The focus of both Mehrling and Pozsar is about thinking ahead to what all that might look like, and that is a positive development in that someone beside those who don’t know what they are doing is actually and crediblypioneering what is really new territory.

My focus is and has been on the actual shift from B to C; after all, getting from A to B was an enormous near-catastrophe.  Merhling puts together a synopsis of the money markets right now, and it is already divergent from the fantasyland inhabited by FOMC expectations:

This way of thinking may shed light also on the disconnect between the Fed interest forecast and the market interest forecast that we mentioned at the top.  Possibly that difference is not so much about market expectations that the Fed will chicken out, and more about an expected increasing divergence between IOER and other money market rates.  P&S Exhibit 4 shows plainly that the Fed’s RRP rate has provided a floor while IOER has provided a ceiling; Fed Funds effective has been in the middle.   The market thinks that IOER can go up with no consequences for other money market rates.  Even worse, the market thinks that there are trillions of money funding about to be released from bank deposits and prime money funds, which if anything will be driving wholesale money rates down, not up.

While I respectfully disagree about the RRP providing a floor (repo fails, specials and all that), I think his suggestion about the IOER going up with “no consequence for other money market rates” is likely correct.  But I also think the fact that some money rates, including the dead federal funds rate (effective), have already taken flight also suggests another scenario altogether – that B to C could or will be a total mess.  This is essentially the same scenario that I think has been acting out since November 20, 2013.  In other words, there will not be any normalcy, and any attempt to go backward undertakes what amounts to incalculable risk of being disastrous (that is why, I believe, credit market bearishness, flattening yield and money/eurdollar curves, and any number of paradigm inflections in various markets all date back to around November 20; that “something” occurred as a consequence of the taper selloff that more than suggested getting out of QE’s and such was nigh impossible.  That such a sentiment has lasted now almost two years forms the basis of what I have called the Fed’s suicidal tendenciestoward ending ZIRP).

I personally find way too much complacency in blindly believing that going from B to C will be only a minor inconvenience.  It would be dangerous even under the circumstances where the system shifted from the dealers to the Fed and back to the dealers, with an infinite series of potential dangers even there.  But to undertake a total and complete money market reformation from dealers to the Fed to money funds?  There are no tests or history with which to suggest this is even doable under current intentions.  Poszar and Mehrling’s contributions more than suggest that difficulty, but I think that still understates whether or not we ever get that far.

Clearly the entire eurodollar system has been undertaking pains of withdrawal all the way back to August 9, 2007.  What is at issue is what might constitute that second transition, to get from B to C.  Poszar’s scenario is one of a relatively familiar C, with some difficulty in achieving it (largely in the Fed “holding its nose” about the RRP’s) and Mehrling (and I really don’t want to speak too much for him) looking maybe a little past that.  My position is that the transition has already been rocky and with some very dangerous results so far (October 15, January 15).  The Swiss National Bank can attest.

ABOOK May 2015 TIC 6mo Eurodollar

The first rule of military planning is that no plan ever survives first contact; in money market planning we have already seen the metaphorical bullets all over the place.  That may not necessarily derail the intended transformation, but I wouldn’t discount that in the end what comes out looks nothing like even the C’s envisioned here.  After all, heading toward late 2007, hardly anyone could see that A would prove so unworkable as to force even shifting to B, and that B looked nothing like what anyone dreamed it would.  Paradigm shifts are alwaysmessy, and financial and funding markets since November 20, 2013, have been getting more and more nervous about it all.  In many ways that is understandable given the gathering preponderance of unknown unknowns coming into view, but also as a matter of wider appreciation that they don’t know what they are doing.